Risk In Capitalism
✑ CHRIS DILLOW` ╱ ± 5 minutes
In this crisis, it is workers and small businesses who bear risk to a greater extent. It is only the culmination of several long-term trends which have seen capital de-risk in recent years at the expense of workers.
The idea that the boss of a large firm is a swashbuckling risk-taker is a fiction.
In this crisis, it is workers and small businesses who bear risk to a greater extent. It is only the culmination of several long-term trends which have seen capital de-risk in recent years at the expense of workers.
From: Stumbling and Mumbling (Chris Dillow), April 24, 2020. ╱ About the author
Chris Dillow was born in Leicester in 1963. He went to Wyggeston Boys School (a grammar), Corpus Christi College, Oxford, and the University of Manchester. He then drifted into the City for a few years before joining the Investors Chronicle, though he strenuously denies accusations that he's a journalist. Chris lives alone in Belsize Park, and blogs at Stumbling and Mumbling. On twitter: @CJFDillow.
One thing this crisis is demonstrating is that in modern capitalism it is
workers and small businesses that bear risk to a greater extent that does
larger capital.
As Paul Evans points out, some of the biggest losers are freelance workers who are ineligible for furlough schemes. And Charles Gascon at the St Louis Fed adds that it is low-paid workers who are most at risk of losing their jobs:
By contrast, most asset-owners could with only moderate care have avoided big losses; in the IC, I’ve shown that simple diversified portfolios have lost only tiny sums.
This contrast is the culmination of several long-term trends which have seen capital de-risk in recent years at the expense of workers. For example:
This raises two questions. One is: what function, then, do capitalists fulfil?
It is certainly not the provision of finance capital. Governments can do this cheaper and in greater abundance, as Rishi Sunak implicitly acknowledged this week with his plan to support innovative businesses. Nor is it clear that they effectively finance smaller firms. The stock of UK bank lending to manufacturing SMEs is a mere 9.4bn. That means that for every pound banks have lent to small manufacturers they have lent £155 in mortgages on houses.
Instead, increasingly, capitalists simply supply platforms. They act as middlemen connecting workers to other workers and to customers.
A second question this poses is: who should own firms? Common sense says that owners should be those with the most skin in the game. If you have most to lose from a firm going bust you have the biggest incentive to ensure that it doesn’t. This points to a case for subcontractors, freelancers and workers to have equity stakes – especially to the extent that they supply firm-specific capital and skills. As it is, current ownership structures give big capital exposure to upside risk whilst its workers and freelancers who face the most downside risk.
What we have here might yet another example of how ideas can outlive their evidence base. We still think of capitalists as like Victorian mill-owners who face the risk of ruin if their investments fail, and so are entitled to ownership and rewards on that account. But this is no longer the case. We must ask: what exactly is it that capitalists do and does this justify – even on narrow grounds of efficiency – their ownership?
As Paul Evans points out, some of the biggest losers are freelance workers who are ineligible for furlough schemes. And Charles Gascon at the St Louis Fed adds that it is low-paid workers who are most at risk of losing their jobs:
The occupations at the highest risk of unemployment also tend to be
lower-paid occupations. The average annual earnings of the low-risk
occupations is $64,600, about 75% higher than earnings in the high-risk
occupations, at $36,600. This indicates the economic burden from this
health crisis will most directly affect those workers who are likely in
the most vulnerable financial situation.
The UK is unlikely to be much different.
By contrast, most asset-owners could with only moderate care have avoided big losses; in the IC, I’ve shown that simple diversified portfolios have lost only tiny sums.
This contrast is the culmination of several long-term trends which have seen capital de-risk in recent years at the expense of workers. For example:
- The shift to a two-tier workforce with a core of staff and periphery of gig workers and freelancers means that companies can more easily shift cyclical risk onto workers. As Paul says, firms have “managed to shovel all of the risk related to their industry down the pipe to freelancers.”
- Some workers are now in fact capitalists in the sense that they supply capital – for example freelance sound mixers supply their own expensive kit; Uber drivers take on debt to supply cabs; and some delivery drivers must supply their own vans and uniform. This exposes them not just to ordinary job risks, but also to the dangers of losing a capital investment.
- Some capitalists make themselves secured creditors which means they lose little when “their” business fails, whilst the cost falls upon workers and subcontractors – as we saw, for example, with the collapse of Carillion .
- As Rene Stulz and Kathleen Kahle have shown , stock market listed companies have become older, bigger and more cash-rich in recent years: this is true of the UK as well as US. This means the typical equity investment is less risky than it used to be.
- The closure of final salary schemes means that the investment risk
involved in saving for retirement has been transferred from firms to
workers, even though they are
unable
to carry such risk efficiently.
- UK companies generally have derisked their balance sheets since the financial crisis. Bank of England data show that their (sterling) cash holdings have doubled since then, and that non-financial firms now hold more cash than debt. (This is partly a reflection of the growing importance of intangible assets, though whether these are any riskier than tangible assets such as machinery is moot.)
- The shift towards monetary activism and fiscal conservatism tends to benefit asset holders (especially leveraged ones) more than workers, as asset prices benefit from low interest rates and QE.
This raises two questions. One is: what function, then, do capitalists fulfil?
It is certainly not the provision of finance capital. Governments can do this cheaper and in greater abundance, as Rishi Sunak implicitly acknowledged this week with his plan to support innovative businesses. Nor is it clear that they effectively finance smaller firms. The stock of UK bank lending to manufacturing SMEs is a mere 9.4bn. That means that for every pound banks have lent to small manufacturers they have lent £155 in mortgages on houses.
Instead, increasingly, capitalists simply supply platforms. They act as middlemen connecting workers to other workers and to customers.
A second question this poses is: who should own firms? Common sense says that owners should be those with the most skin in the game. If you have most to lose from a firm going bust you have the biggest incentive to ensure that it doesn’t. This points to a case for subcontractors, freelancers and workers to have equity stakes – especially to the extent that they supply firm-specific capital and skills. As it is, current ownership structures give big capital exposure to upside risk whilst its workers and freelancers who face the most downside risk.
What we have here might yet another example of how ideas can outlive their evidence base. We still think of capitalists as like Victorian mill-owners who face the risk of ruin if their investments fail, and so are entitled to ownership and rewards on that account. But this is no longer the case. We must ask: what exactly is it that capitalists do and does this justify – even on narrow grounds of efficiency – their ownership?
Top image: U.S. Secretary of Commerce Donald L. Evans rings the opening bell at the New York Stock Exchange on April 23, 2003. From: Wikimedia. |
---|
Comments
Post a Comment
Your thoughts...